Showing posts with label reforms. Show all posts
Showing posts with label reforms. Show all posts

Friday, October 8, 2021

Telecom Reforms: Relief - With Hope?


 

This could be a good first step towards a real transformation.

  Shyam Ponappa    |   October 7, 2021


At first glance, the big-bang telecom relief package last month might seem disappointing. A closer look shows the possibility of real promise. Could it be a subtle masterstroke, the first in a series of steps that will revive the sector? Here’s why.

  • By not fully resolving the debt burden to result in sustainable cash flows, it gives the impression of a grudging debt-restructuring that doesn’t quite revive the patient, while prolonging the agony.

  • However, it provides immediate relief with a four-year moratorium on cash outflows.

  • An issue that defied resolution since 2003, of what constitutes revenues for sharing, has been defined rationally as revenues from telecom.

  • The spectrum usage charge has been rescinded.

  • Solutions for revival are to be worked out as next steps.

Although the last three are prospective, telcos get immediate relief without awaiting the formulation of complex solutions. The relief is temporary though, as outstanding dues must be paid with interest. Unless much more is done, there will be a prolonged attrition, with high opportunity costs from the continuing non-availability of services that severely constrain our capacity and productivity.

Meanwhile, another significant reform was introduced unobtrusively: Active network sharing. Blocking active sharing amounts to depriving the country of full utilisation of capital-intensive resources. Imagine having separate private road systems, or gas pipelines, and insisting that vehicles (or gas) must go from place to place only on their own networks. This was the situation in telecom until interconnection was made mandatory, but the latter did not eliminate network duplication, whereas active network sharing allows for eliminating it.

Thereafter, news that the government may change its position on spectrum charges due suggests more pragmatism. If the above interpretation is correct, the subtlety and quick action while avoiding opposition by not seeming to give away too much augur well.

For transformative reforms and a genuine revival, the Ministry of Communications and Information Technology could take the approach that worked reasonably well for NTP-99, with coordinated planning and initiatives through the PMO across ministries and corporations, and external advice as appropriate. While it was not perfect, the NTP-99’s adoption of revenue sharing succeeded in expanding mobile telephony enormously. Learning from that experience in handling the details may help to avoid situations such as the legal wrangles on the scope of revenues, and the false starts. For instance, the government’s share was set too high initially at 15 per cent, and thereafter, spectrum auctions after the “2G scam” crippled the sector because of the “winner’s curse”, as auctions did in much of the world. We had best avoid such situations.

Wi-Fi Small Cells

The ongoing evolution to small cells amplifies the need for sharing. Mobile handoff to Wi-Fi is already the norm for 4G. Ubiquitous 4G networks and later upgrade to 5G and 6G will require the installation of many more small cells, with Wi-Fi for high-speed user access. These could augment existing Wi-Fi bands (2.4 and 5 GHz) with 6 GHz and 60 GHz when these bands are permitted. Proliferation of small cells will be more feasible because of lower costs and easier installation with wireless point-to-point links instead of fibre, and mandatory sharing. “Wireless fibre” links could use light-licensed (open access to licensed service providers for connecting to the internet) spectrum in the 60 GHz (V-band) and 70-80 GHz (E-band). Gigabit delivery at far lower cost than fibre could be deployed across urban, semi-urban, and rural markets.

Small cells for users need to be built out with “wireless fibre” links from where fibre terminates in much of the country, in urban as well as rural areas. An alternative depending on costs is satellite links to small cells. In effect, the need is for the national fibre network, BharatNet, to be extended to non-urban users outside district and block headquarters. Small cells funded by the Universal Service Obligation Fund combined with the BSNL’s and other installed networks could fulfill this need, with service providers given non-discriminatory access on payment through revenue sharing. A consortium approach with private sector leads could be considered.

Shared Spectrum & Infrastructure

A burdensome remaining constraint for network proliferation is licensed spectrum costs. Yet, the alternative of giving access to a spectrum pool without auctions for a share of revenues would probably result in much higher government revenues, as happened with licence fees after NTP-99 (see charts).

Chart 1: Operator Revenues ($ Billion)

https://www.ibef.org/download/Telecommunications-June-2020.pdf

Chart 2: Revenue Share Collections Exceed Auction Payments After NTP-99

          Telecom Auction Fees Foregone vs Licence Fees + Spectrum Charges


For explanation, see: https://organizing-india.blogspot.com/2020/08/configuring-indias-digital-ecosystem.html

Shared access by licensed telcos to pooled spectrum will enable broadband for more areas and people, with full utilisation of unused spectrum greatly increasing traffic and revenues. The DoT needs to start with regulations for spectrum bands in 60 GHz, 70-80 GHz, and 6 GHz. Thereafter, regulations could be considered for shared spectrum without auctions. (1)

Debt Resolution for Cash Flows

An immediate priority for the sector is sustainable cash flows. The burden of adjusted gross revenue (AGR) and spectrum usage dues arose from misconceived policy errors, by efforts to include unrelated revenues, and overcharging for spectrum. Debt restructuring customarily involves elements such as reduced principal (“haircuts”), interest waivers, and extension of repayment periods, to enable sustainable cash flows. Much of the principal for AGR dues was created by including revenues unrelated to the licences to be paid for, an error corrected going forward. Past licence-related revenues would be much less, and favourable judgments prior to 2019 upheld this. The interest component in AGR dues is about three times the principal. The government could justifiably adopt policies to reduce most or all outstandings with this reasoning, as also consideration of the effort, cost and hardship endured by service providers, their employees, and the public for service deprivation of the critical support that broadband can/could have provide/(d). Further, this would also facilitate investment for better services.

Corrective Policies, Laws, Regulations

A participative process on these issues starting with debt resolution could be used to frame policies going forward, including the requisite legislation and regulations. The above measures can revive and invigorate our telecom sector.


Shyam (no space) Ponappa at gmail dot com

(1): See “Enable Spectrum Usage on Feasible Terms” at:  https://organizing-india.blogspot.com/2020/03/indias-self-goal-in-telecom.html


Monday, June 5, 2017

Broadband Reforms for Local Manufacturing + Coverage

Published as "Broadband reforms for local manufacturing".

Broadband in India needs reforms for local manufacturing and for infrastructure expansion and utilisation.

Shyam Ponappa 
  |   June 1, 2017


India’s markets are at the heart of what attracts investment and economic activity, with mobile phones and broadband services comprising a significant share. In exploring their magnitude and supply chains, an obvious need emerges for policies and incentives for local manufacturing of components and handsets to boost domestic supply and create employment. Another avenue for deriving local benefits is extending the coverage of digital platforms, expanding the market through policies and incentives facilitating broadband infrastructure. Policy support can help both to extend networks using fixed and wireless technologies, as well as to increase capacity utilisation.


Reforms affecting both supply and demand are needed to fully and equitably provide ubiquitous coverage and exploit digital platforms for public welfare. Such reforms would mitigate the lower revenue potential of rural populations. Enabling steps could include allowing active sharing of spectrum and networks, providing more unlicensed spectrum, financial incentives such as tax credits and spectrum charge rebates for rural infrastructure, and standardised right-of-way charges.  


India’s Mobile Handset Market


“A billion smartphones will be sold in India in [the] next five years.”


This estimate is from a report by IIM-Bangalore and CounterPoint Researchers.1 The report notes that India became the second-largest global smartphone market in terms of number of users in early 2016, and still has enormous growth potential even as demand for smartphones elsewhere is waning. In the next five years, almost a billion smartphones and half a billion feature phones will require components worth $80 billion (Rs 5.2 lakh crore). These will have to be imported if they are not produced locally. The report estimates that in 2016, about 50 local units assembled over 180 million mobile phones valued at $9 billion (about Rs 59,000 crore), about 70 per cent of the $13 billion sold. However, the local value addition was only $650 million (Rs 4,225 crore, or 7.2 per cent). This underscores an urgent need for policy changes, considering that emerging manufacturers in these sectors such as  Brazil and Vietnam have value added of nearly 20 per cent and over 30 per cent, respectively, while champions such as South Korea and Taiwan add above 50 per cent, and China has 70 per cent local value added. 


In early 2016, India’s domestic smartphones had a 40 per cent market share, but by the quarter ending March 2017, Chinese brands dominated, with a share of over 51 per cent, while local brands dropped to under 14 per cent.2


According to the IIM-B/CounterPoint Researchers report, Indian manufacturers import most of their components, and there are few incentives for R&D or to attract component suppliers to form local ecosystems. Further, the existing incentives will become ineffective once the goods and services tax (GST) is introduced, because they will all be subsumed under GST. Accordingly, the Broadband India Forum in association with EY have suggested (a) refunding the GST to manufacturers for handsets and (b) extending this policy to components could provide an appropriate manufacturing incentive.3 This needs to be done without delay.4

The report also proposes a phased approach to maximise local value added, aiming for 30 per cent by 2020, and more thereafter. Early phases suggested are moving from assembling chargers and other such accessories to high-value components such as printed circuit boards, cameras and display units. The researchers suggest that chargers, batteries and cameras can in fact be manufactured locally, contributing to components valued at an estimated $15 billion by 2020. If these proposals are adopted and executed, it will reduce imports and create jobs, deriving local benefits from India’s market opportunities. Moreover, it will help create an R&D capability in India for this sector, which can over time become a supplier to global markets.


The prerequisite for these improvements is policy reforms on matters such as duties on components (including the refund of GST) and incentives for suppliers to set up in India. The report also suggests that policies need to be framed for effectively funding institutions and corporations for research to build intellectual property and skilled professionals. 


Extending Digital Infrastructure & Utilisation


There is a parallel need for policies supporting the extension and coverage of digital platforms, of the sort achieved in migrating from up-front auction fees to revenue sharing with the New Telecom Policy in 1999 (NTP-99). These require convergent action within the government and its multifarious departments and agencies, or in some cases by coordination and resolution among stakeholders, i.e., in addition to the agencies of government, the judiciary, the operators and vendors of equipment, the press and media, and the public. 


There are some issues that relate to the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India’s (Trai) recommendations over the years that need decisions on implementation. An example is access to broadband services through cable networks. The government’s position on additional charges as a share of revenues conflicts with cable operators’ unwillingness to pay additional charges, and perhaps the cost of the devices for conversion. The effect of this deadlock is that the entire set of cable network users have to use another means for broadband connectivity. As this policy change will affect the competitive dynamics of wireless service providers, it is a candidate for coordinated, participative resolution. Some Trai recommendations may benefit from review, such as open access (like Wi-Fi) on 60 GHz.


Other examples are: 


  • Enabling additional bands of unused spectrum such as 60 GHz and 70/80 GHz for wireless gigabit links, and 
  • Enabling the sharing of entire networks, including the radio access network (and therefore spectrum) among operators.


The promise of digital platforms is immense, and both these streams of reforms need to be taken up and completed for India’s digital platforms and markets to deliver on their considerable potential.

Shyam (no space) Ponappa at gmail dot com

Added after publication - June 6, 2017
4. For a detailed exposition of the GST question and why raising customs duties on imported equipment/components is not feasible because of the terms of the Information Technology Agreement 1997 under the WTO, see: https://www.linkedin.com/pulse/incentivising-manufacturing-mobile-phones-india-parag-kar